Inflationary Pressures in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram
Inflation fluctuates in the short run. Higher inflation rates have typically occurred either during or just after economic booms; for example, the biggest spurts of inflation in the U.S. economy during the twentieth century followed the wartime booms of World War I and World War II. Conversely, rates of inflation generally decline during recessions. As an extreme example, inflation actually became negative—a situation called deflation—during the Great Depression. Even during the relatively short recession of 1991–1992, the rate of inflation declined from 5.4 percent in 1990 to 3 percent in 1992. During the relatively short recession of 2001, the rate of inflation declined from 3.4 percent in 2000 to 1.6 percent in 2002. During the deep recession of 2007–2009, the rate of inflation declined from 3.8 percent in 2008 to 0.4 percent in 2009. Some countries have experienced bouts of high inflation that lasted for years. In the U.S. economy since the mid-1980s, inflation does not seem to have had any long-term trend to be substantially higher or lower; instead, it has stayed in the range of 1–5 percent annually.
Link It Up
Visit this website for data on business confidence.
The AD/AS framework implies two ways that inflationary pressures may arise. One possible trigger is if AD continues to shift to the right when the economy is already at or near potential GDP and full employment, thus pushing the macroeconomic equilibrium into the steep portion of the AS curve. In Figure 10.10 (a), there is a shift of AD to the right; the new equilibrium E1 is clearly at a higher price level than the original equilibrium E0. In this situation, the AD in the economy has soared so high that firms in the economy are not capable of producing additional goods, because labor and physical capital are fully employed, and so additional increases in AD can only result in a rise in the price level.
An alternative source of inflationary pressures can occur due to a rise in input prices that affects many or most firms across the economy—perhaps an important input to production like oil or labor—and causes the AS curve to shift back to the left. In Figure 10.10 (b), the shift of the SRAS curve to the left also increases the price level from P0 at the original equilibrium (E0) to a higher price level of P1 at the new equilibrium (E1). In effect, the rise in input prices ends up, after the final output is produced and sold, being passed along in the form of a higher price level for outputs.
The AD/AS diagram shows only a one-time shift in the price level. It does not address the question of what would cause inflation either to vanish after a year, or to sustain itself for several years. There are two explanations for why inflation may persist over time. One way that continual inflationary price increases can occur is if the government continually attempts to stimulate aggregate demand in a way that keeps pushing the AD curve when it is already in the steep portion of the SRAS curve. A second possibility is that, if inflation has been occurring for several years, a certain level of inflation may come to be expected. For example, if consumers, workers, and businesses all expect prices and wages to rise by a certain amount, then these expected rises in the price level can become built into the annual increases of prices, wages, and interest rates of the economy. These two reasons are interrelated, because if a government fosters a macroeconomic environment with inflationary pressures, then people will grow to expect inflation. However, the AD/AS diagram does not show these patterns of ongoing or expected inflation in a direct way.